The
Dutch Revolt
Revolution
the Long Way
A
Note on Origins Part I
In 1566 there began one of the first of
the modern revolutions and still likely the longest. The Dutch Revolt started
in 1566 and didn’t end until 1648. The war also showed the usual pattern of
revolution and counterrevolution in this case expressed in geographical terms.
The two geographical entities that were created by the revolt were The
Netherlands and Belgium.
The Netherlands were the state created
by the revolution. Belgium was the state created by the counter-revolution.
The roots of the revolution in the Low
Countries go back a long way before 1566. They in fact go back to the rise of
the towns of Flanders and Hainaut in the 12th and 13th
centuries that created the self-confident class of merchant oligarchs that
governed the cities and grew rich on trade and finance.
The source of the finance was mainly the
trade from Germany and the Baltic that traveled overland and by sea to the
region of the Low Countries and then was processed and / or redistributed to
other areas of Europe. In exchange the merchants of Flanders and related areas
exported finished merchandise to eastern Europe, such as finished textiles, and
luxury objects.1
The growing wealth and power of the
cities of the low countries was reflected in the growth of political influence
and economic and military power. Perhaps the most telling indication was the
battle of Courtrai in 1302 In which a coalition of the cities of Flanders
crushingly defeated the Count of Flanders and his French allies in a battle
that degenerated into a massacre of nobility.2
Subsequent to that over the next century
and a half the rising economic power of the cities led to them frequently
forming leagues and fighting the attempts of their feudal overlords to impose
control. In the end the feudal over lords, first the Dukes of Burgundy and then
the Habsburgs were able to reassert control over their recalcitrant cities.3
Although in the end the cities retained considerable political and economic
independence, with power in the hands of local wealthy oligarchs.
Most of this early development, economic
and political came in the southern cities, located in modern day Belgium of the
regions of Flanders and Hainaut. Flanders being part of the kingdom of France
and Hainaut being part of the Holy Roman Empire. In the late 15th century Flanders
and Artois fell out of the French kingdom and became Habsburg possessions and
part of the Holy Roman Empire.4
Further in the late 15th and
early 16th century the province of Holland began through its trade
connections and its fishing fleet to experience significant economic growth
with the rise of self-governing towns ruled by merchant oligarchs.5
The final piece in the puzzle was the
long reign of Charles V, (1519-1556 C.E.) of the house of Habsburg who through
his grandmother Mary of Burgundy inherited among other things much of the low
countries. In the area affected by the later revolution Charles inherited Artois,
Flanders, Hainaut, Namur, Brabant, Luxemburg, Holland and Zealand. Throughout
his reign Charles was anxious to round out his possessions so he endeavored to
add to his possessions so that they would become a geographical whole. Thus he
added Utrecht, Gelderland, Drenthe / Overijssel, Friesland and Goningen &
Ommelanden.6
Charles V endeavored to impose some sort
of political unity on this assortment of states and among the common political
institutions he created for them was the so-called States-General. A Parliament
like institution that included representatives from all the constituent
provinces that made up what was called the low countries.7
This bid to rationalize the political
institutions was not made because of some sort of awareness of an ethnic unity
of peoples. In fact the reason seemed to be administrative convenience. In fact
the provinces had been in the past frequently at war with each other, they had
no unity by language, ethnicity or similarity of economic development.
In terms of language In the southern
part of this “unity” created by Charles V, much of the population spoke
Walloonian French. This included Artois, Hainaut, Namur and most of Luxemburg.
In Flanders, Brabant, Holland and Utrecht the population spoke Dutch and Dutch
was the most commonly spoken language in the low countries. In Friesland the
population spoke Frisian, and in most of Gelderland, Drenthe et al, and
Groningen et al the population spoke Oosters. In much of Luxemburg and along
the eastern boundary of the low countries much of the population spoke low
German.
Only recently united in any sense,
linguistically and politically divided into different provinces with different
and not shared histories the provinces were further divided economically.
Holland, Flanders and Brabant were
economically advanced, with well-developed trade, a market economy in
agriculture produces, advanced fisheries and an advanced manufacturing and
financial sector. Artois, Hainault and Friesland were fairly advanced in terms
of agricultural development but not as advanced in trade and manufacturing as
the provinces like Holland. Drenthe et al, Gelderland and Groningen were
economically backwards in nearly all respects and quite poor. Luxemburg was
above Drenthe et al but still not wealthy.8
Trying to impose unity on this diverse
in so many ways conglomerate of political units would have been a challenge for
the most perfect of diplomats, but then we add the ingredient of religious
conflict and the whole thing becomes impossible.
In this case the added factor which made
the whole thing explode into revolution and then counter-revolution was
religion. In this case the Reformation. In the Netherlands all the factors
making for discontent with the rule of the Habsburg’s began to coalesce around the
issue of religion. The Protestant Reformation brought gave something that those
discontented with the way things were in the Netherlands something to rally
around and give a focus to their discontent. It also upped the level of tension
and hysteria by one level of magnitude.
For
aside from giving those who were discontented a focus and increasing the tension
level massively it also gave those who wanted the status quo to continue
something to focus against. In this case the status quo faith was Catholicism.
And it added a level of religious self-righteousness and hysterical fervor to
the denunciations and opposition to the revolutionaries.9
Thus the religious components had a
minority on both sides propelled by self-righteous religious fanaticism.
This factor compounded and made murderously
lethal the various divisions of the Netherlands and resulted in a revolution
and war of quite fearful barbarity and of long duration.
Chronically disunited, only recently
united politically the likelihood of a revolution being turned into a bloody
stalemate between revolution and counter-revolution was very high.
In terms of proximate causes perhaps the
most germane cause was that the imposition of a united central administrative structure
was the signal for the central authority, i.e., the Habsburg’s to try to
rationalize and streamline the political and administrative system in the low
countries. What this meant was an erosion of the “privileges and immunities”
i.e., “rights” enjoyed by the various provinces of the low countries. It was
through these ‘rights” that the oligarchs, nobility and wealthy merchants who
dominated the politics of the various provinces exercised their power and
control over the political and administrative systems of the various provinces.
Any attempt to change that was perceived,
by the nobles and wealthy merchants, largely correctly, as an attack on their
position and powers, which were to be shifted to a centralized bureaucracy
based in Brussels. Not surprisingly they resented such innovations, especially when
it came in the form of taxation that by passed traditional institutions in
terms of how it was collected and spent.10
Thus beginning in the 1550’s mounting
religious, economic and political tensions made the situation fairly volatile
with religion being the explosive force to set off revolution.
I will continue another time other
aspects of the origins of the Dutch Revolt.
1. Parker, Geoffrey, The Dutch Revolt, Penguin Books,
London, 1977, pp. 19-30, Elliott, J.H., Europe
Divided 1559-1598, Fontana,
London, 1968, pp. 125-138.
2. Holmes, George, Europe: Hierarchy and Revolt 1320-1450, Fontana, London, 1975, pp.
21, 31.
3. IBID, pp. 130-133.
4. Elliott, J.H., Imperial Spain, 1469-1716, Penguin Books, London, 1963, pp.
135-144.
5. Parker, 1977, pp. 19-30.
6. IBID, Elliott, 1968, pp. 48-50.
7. Parker, 1977, pp. 30-35.
8. IBID, Elliott, 1968, pp. 19-30.
9. Parker, 1977, pp. 40-55, Elliott,
1968, pp. 134-144.
10. IBID, Parker, 1977, 56-67, Parker,
Geoffrey, The Grand Strategy of Philip
II, Yale University Press, New Haven
CONN, 1998, pp. 115-121.
Pierre Cloutier
No comments:
Post a Comment